In rural labor markets, a tied-labor contract involves a long-term relationship between
an employer and a worker where the employer provides a steady but low wage to the
worker (relative to a casual labor contract that offers a high wage rate during the
harvest season). The role of labor-tying on terms of labor contracts has been stud-
ied extensively in theoretical studies (Bardhan (1983), Eswaran and Kotwal (1985),
Mukherjee and Ray (1995)) and the empirical relevance of tied-labor has been shown,
particularly in South Asia1 (Bardhan and Rudra (1978)). In developing countries where
poor households face substantial amounts of risk and limited insurance opportunities,
labor-tying is likely to be an important channel through which they smooth their in-
come, hence their consumption2 (Morduch (1995)). Yet recent empirical studies have
mainly focused on other mechanisms of consumption-smoothing such as informal in-
surance and pre-cautionary savings3. Using original survey data from Bangladesh, I
show that labor-tying is an important mechanism through which poor workers smooth
their consumption. Furthermore, I test the effects of an experiment that increases the
expected income of the poor women living in rural Bangladesh on their involvement
in tied labor. In particular, I show that an exogenous improvement in the outside
option of poor workers decreases their participation in tied-labor, and allows them to
enter labor contracts with higher return but higher income volatility. This change in
the level and composition of labor supply within the village has different general equilibrium effects on the returns to tied and casual labor in the male and female labor
markets within the village. Finally, I provide evidence that suggests that the treated
poor households are changing the mechanisms through which they smooth their con-
sumption. In particular, the households that are exogenously made wealthier are less
likely to engage in tied-labor arrangements, but more likely to form reciprocal transfer
links with other villagers. Taken all together, the findings show that as poor households
(exogenously) get richer, they move from second-best labor contracts (that yield a low
return but insure them against risks) to more profitable yet riskier income generating
activities, accompanied with reciprocal transfer arrangements that help smooth their
consumption.
I use this theoretical framework to test the effects of an exogenous increase in the
outside option of poorest workers on their participation in tied labor and on the terms
of labor contracts in the village economy. The exogenous variation I exploit is the
randomized roll-out of the “ultra poor” program in Bangladesh. The “ultra poor”
program was pioneered by BRAC4 and targets the poorest women living in villages. It
involves a combination of a large asset transfer (livestock or trees), enterprize training
and weekly visits by program officers to ensure that the treated females are able to
generate income from the assets that they receive. In short, the program improves the
self-employment opportunities of treated women. The data used in this paper comes
from the randomized evaluation of BRAC’s ultra poor program in Bangladesh. The program identifies the poorest females living in rural villages, who are often landless
laborers. They rely primarily on finding work as agricultural day-laborers or maids,
and on the transfers they receive from the rest of the community. This is a setting
where seasonal fluctuations in wage earnings are very significant (see Figure 1) and a
large proportion of the targeted poor households enter into tied-labor contracts that
provide a smoother income profile but lower average wage.
In order to test the predictions of the model empirically, I make use of two key
characteristics of the evaluation strategy: First, in order to identify tied and casual
workers empirically, I use data on the identity of workers’ employers and their food transfer links. The data is unique in the sense that for every business activity that the
respondents were engaged in, they were asked to report the identity of their employer
and as long as the employer was within the same village (as the respondent), their
household ID number was recorded. Similarly, respondents were asked to identify the
most important 3 households they would borrow food from at times of need. Using
these two pieces of information, I can identify which employers were also a borrowing
source for the worker: 25% of the poor workers report their employer as a source of
food transfers in times of need. I show that this definition of tied labor contracts also
correlates with having lower average wage rate and lower wage volatility, in line with
the definition of tied labor contracts in the theoretical framework5.
I start by analyzing the effects of the program on the treated women. I find that
the program has a negative impact on the participation of treated females in the female
labor market in the village. They are 10% less likely to be working for another household
in the village at followup relative to eligible women in control villages. This suggests
that there is an overall fall in the labor supply in the female labor market in the village.
In line with prediction 2, conditional on being in wage employment, treated females are
20% less likely to be in tied-labor contracts. Hence there is a greater fall in the supply
of tied female workers relative to casual workers. Furthermore, this suggests that the
direct effect of the program on the outside options of treated women dominates any
indirect GE effects through the labor markets.
In order to formalize the incentives of workers and employers in entering tied-labor
arrangements, I adopt the risk-sharing model of labor-tying developed by Bardhan
(1983) where a risk-averse worker enters into a tied labor arrangement with a risk-
neutral employer in order to smooth her income during the lean and peak seasons.
Alternatively, the worker can choose to settle down for her expected outside option,
which will be a function of her wealth and vulnerability (proneness to risks). The
model assumes that tied workers and casual laborers are perfect substitutes in the farm
production function during the peak season. Hence, the employer’s only incentive in
offering tied-labor contracts is to ensure supply of cheap labor during the peak season.
In equilibrium, it will be the poorest and most vulnerable workers that enter into tied-
labor contracts, while better-off workers will choose to remain self-employed and work
for the employer as a casual worker whenever the realized village market wage rate
exceeds their expected outside option. This automatically implies that casual workers
will receive a higher wage rate on average.
The theoretical model gives the following predictions with respect to an exogenous
shock to the outside options of the poorest workers in the economy:
-
In partial equilibrium (assuming there is no effect on the returns to tied or casual
labor)
-
(a) Treated workers will be less likely to be working for a wage. This depends
on two factors: (i) whether the amount of increase in the outside option of
the treated worker is large enough (ii) the initial level of the outside option
of the worker.
-
(b) Conditional on remaining in wage-employment, treated workers will be less
likely to be in tied-labor contracts and more likely to be in casual labor
contracts.
-
(a) Treated workers will be less likely to be working for a wage. This depends
on two factors: (i) whether the amount of increase in the outside option of
the treated worker is large enough (ii) the initial level of the outside option
of the worker.
-
In general equilibrium, depending on how the program affects the aggregate dis-
tribution of workers’ outside options, wages for both tied and casual laborers may
increase. In that case, the threshold level of outside option below which workers
enter into tied contracts also increases.
-
A corollary of prediction (2) is that the effect of the program on whether treated
workers remain in wage-work and the type of contracts they enter will be am-
biguous in general equilibrium. The direct effect on their outside options and the
GE effects through the labor market have opposing effects on their labor market
participation.
-
Finally, if workers are matched assortatively by their outside options in reciprocal
transfer arrangements, then treated workers will be more likely to enter reciprocal
arrangements with wealthier workers to smooth their consumption. This will
increase their likelihood to switch from tied to casual labor contracts.
Second, in order to identify the direct effects of the program on the treated house-
holds and the indirect spillover effects on non-treated households via the labor market,
I make use of the fact that the program was randomized at the village level and the
sample includes both treated and non-treated workers in treatment and control villages.
Comparison of treated workers in treatment villages to those workers that were selected
for treatment but were not treated in control villages (henceforth “selected workers”)
allows me to identify the direct effect of the program combined with any indirect general
equilibrium effects. By comparing the non-treated workers in treatment villages to the
relevant group of workers in control villages, I identify the general equilibrium effects
of the program on the rest of the community.
No hay comentarios:
Publicar un comentario